Let’s be clear about transparency

Share with your friends










Submit

Transparency—or its absence—continues to fascinate healthcare analysts and healthcare economists.  A study just published in the Annals of Internal Medicine addresses the effects of public reporting of hospital mortality rates on outcomes.  Its senior author, Dr. Ashish Jha, offered his perspective on the study results and on the topic of transparency in The Health Care Blog.

According to the study investigators, mandatory public reporting of hospital mortality is not improving outcomes.  The result of their analysis surprised them because “the notion behind transparency is straightforward” and the “logic [of public reporting] is sound.”  The conclusion, therefore, is to persist in the effort, but to do it better with better metrics, better methods, and better data.  Says Dr. Jha:

So, the bottom line is this – if transparency is worth doing, why not do it right? Who knows, it might even make care better and create greater trust in the healthcare system.

Now, I have no doubt about the sincere desire of healthcare analysts to improve our lot, but I wonder if they have reflected on a certain pattern that emerges if one studies the history of our healthcare system.

Starting with the establishment of licensing laws, which were precisely enacted to “create greater trust in the healthcare system,” we’ve lived through repeating cycles of unintended negative consequences followed by new regulatory impositions backed by “straightforward arguments” and “sound logic.”  One would think that history alone would give one pause or temper one’s enthusiasm for renewed efforts at doing more of the same.

But when it comes to the particular question of transparency, there is an additional aspect that eludes most analysts.  They don’t realize that the absence of transparency is precisely the result of government intervention and healthcare policy.  It is because healthcare has become a boondoggle, an inextricable mishmash of privileges given to various—and often competing—special interests, that no one has any serious incentive to be upfront about what is really going on in-house.

Take price transparency, for example. When providers of goods and services compete in an unhampered market, are they opaque about prices?  Of course, not.  Price opacity would immediately elicit distrust from customers.  Should this be any different in healthcare?  There is no reason to think so, and if you have any doubt,  learn about the Surgery Center of Oklahoma which offers absolute and guaranteed price transparency precisely because it operates as a free-market service.

In a free and competitive healthcare market, price transparency would rarely be an issue, as it is not an issue in the market for cell phones and bubble gum.  Doctors and hospitals could not survive without being upfront about fees.  But, in its great wisdom, and supported by the sound logic of healthcare analysts and healthcare economists, the government has ensured—through its tampering with and participation in health insurance—that charges would be as opaque as possible.

The same goes for transparency about the quality of care, except that the question here is orders of magnitude more complex, as quality can never be reduced to measurable metrics.  Besides, another unexamined assumption skews the outlook of analysts: the assumption that the public is entirely incapable of judging medical quality on its own, but needs government-appointed intermediaries to accomplish the task.

But here again, the appointment of intermediaries by the government is and has always been subject to manipulation and to political pressure.  When healthcare spending is in the hundreds of billions per year, quality reporting of that sort inevitably becomes a boondoggle subject to “gaming” or corruption.

If healthcare were left alone, it would ultimately be in the interest of providers to ask truly independent rating agencies to bridge any information asymmetry regarding quality and provide those signals that could not be obtained on the basis of reputation or word of mouth alone.  As it stands, the effort of rating agencies is muddled by the fact that the selection of outcomes is usually determined by healthcare analysts, not by the patients, or by the fact that patients have so little influence on their care that their input is limited to superficial considerations.

In a Wall Street Journal blog post published a couple of years ago, Leah Binder, president and CEO of one of the nation’s most prominent patient safety organizations, noted the importance of mutual trust in the doctor-patient relationship.  It is as important for doctors to trust patients as it is for patients to trust doctors, she remarked.

I couldn’t agree more with her on that point.  But trust building is a largely intangible process.  Even though it will be influenced by the availability of objective measures, the value of such measures is largely voided when these must be ferreted out by force.  After all, Binder doesn’t expect doctors to demand from patients evidence of trustworthiness in the name of transparency.

Transparency is a characteristic that people and institutions naturally demonstrate—or not.  It cannot be “obtained” or mandated by policy or regulatory fiat.  Dr. Jha titled his commentary “Making Transparency Work.”  A better title would be “Letting Transparency Be.”

[Related post: “Intolerable” laissez-faire: the early years of the Mayo Clinic]

[Related post: The murky call for transparency]

[Related post: The problem with transparency]

2 Comments

  1. I couldn’t agree with you more. The incestuous relationship between the regulator and regulated introduce strong incentives against transparency as well as barriers to the formation of trust relationships between doctor and patient. There are disincentives to transparency and trust in markets as well but they also encourage the formation of providers that offer information that increase transparency and trust.
    Cellphone carriers are an example of this process.

    1. You’re right. My example saying “cell phones” was ambiguous since the phone itself usually comes attached to a service plan that is hard to comprehend. I should have said “TV sets” which, along with bubble gum, are in much less regulated markets than healthcare or telecom.

Leave a Comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *